Does Inflation a Good or a Bad Thing?
What is
inflation? Inflation is simply an increase in the
average level of prices, and a price is the rate at which money is exchanged
for a good or a service. To understand inflation, therefore, we must understand
money—what it is, what affects its supply and demand, and what influence it has
on the economy.
When
we say that a person has a lot of money, we usually mean that he or she is
wealthy. By contrast, economists use the term “money” in a more specialized
way. To an economist, money does not refer to all wealth but only to one type
of it: money is the stock of assets that can be readily used to make
transactions.
The
Functions of Money
Money
has three purposes: it is a store of value, a unit of account, and a medium of
exchange.
As a store of
value, money is a way to transfer purchasing power from the present to the
future.
As a unit of
account, money provides the terms in which prices are quot-
ed and debts are
recorded.
As a medium of
exchange, money is what we use to buy goods and services.
The quantity of money available in an
economy is called the money supply. In a system of commodity money, the
money supply is simply the quantity of that commodity. In an economy
that uses fiat money, such as most economies today, the government controls the
supply of money: legal restrictions give the government a monopoly on the
printing of money. Just as the level of taxation
and the level of
government purchases are policy instruments of the government, so is the quantity
of money. The government’s control over the money supply is called monetary
policy.
Seigniorage: The
Revenue from Printing Money
all governments spend money. Some
of this spending is to buy goods and services (such as roads and police), and
some is to provide transfer payments (for the poor and elderly, for example). A
government can finance its spending in three ways. First, it can raise revenue through
taxes, such as personal and corporate income taxes. Second, it can borrow from
the public by selling government bonds. Third, it can print money. The revenue
raised by the printing of money is called seigniorage.
When
the government prints money to finance expenditure, it increases the money
supply. The increase in the money supply, in turn, causes inflation. Printing money
to raise revenue is like imposing an inflation tax.
The
amount of revenue raised by printing money varies from country to country. In countries
experiencing hyperinflation, seigniorage is often the government’s chief source
of revenue—indeed, the need to print money to finance expenditure is a primary cause
of hyperinflation.
Hyperinflation
Hyperinflation occurs when a
country experiences very high and usually accelerating rates of inflation,
rapidly eroding the real value of the local currency, and
causing the population to minimize their holdings of local money. The
population normally switches to holding relatively stable foreign currencies.
Under such conditions, the general price level within an economy
increases rapidly as the official currency quickly loses real value.
The Costs of Hyperinflation
The shoeleather costs associated
with reduced money holding, for instance, are serious under hyperinflation.
Business executives devote much time and energy to cash management when cash
loses its value quickly. By diverting this time and energy from more socially
valuable activities, such as production and investment decisions,
hyperinflation makes the economy run less efficiently.
Menu costs also become larger under
hyperinflation. Firms have to change prices so often that normal business
practices, such as printing and distributing catalogs with fixed prices, become
impossible. In one restaurant during the German hyperinflation of the 1920s, a
waiter would stand up on a table every 30 minutes to call out the new prices.
The Causes of Hyperinflation
hyperinflation is caused by excessive growth in the supply of money. When the
central bank prints money, the price level rises. When it prints money rapidly
enough, the result is hyperinflation. To stop the hyperinflation, the central
bank must reduce the rate of money growth.
Conclusion: The Classical Dichotomy
The real
wage is the quantity of output a worker earns for each hour of work, and the
real interest rate is the quantity of output a person earns in the future by
lending one unit of output today. All variables measured in physical units,
such as quantities and relative prices, are called real variables.
nominal
variables—variables
expressed interms of money. The economy has many nominal variables, such as the
price level, the inflation rate, and the dollar wage a person earns.
At first it
may seem surprising that we were able to explain real variables without
introducing nominal variables or the existence of money. In Chapter 3 we
studied the level and allocation of the economy’s output without mentioning the
price level or the rate of inflation. Our theory of the labor market explained
the real wage without explaining the nominal wage. Economists call this
theoretical separation of real and nominal variables the classical
dichotomy. It is the hallmark of classical macroeconomic theory. The
classical dichotomy is an important insight because it simplifies economic
theory. In particular, it allows us to examine real variables, as we have done,
while ignoring nominal variables. The classical dichotomy arises because, in
classical economic theory, changes in the money supply do not influence real
variables. This irrelevance of money for real variables is called monetary
neutrality.
Book : MACROECONOMICS by N. Gregory Mankiw
Komentar
Posting Komentar